Environment for Development
Discussion Paper Series November 2012 EfD DP 12-15
Abalone Conservation in the Presence of Drug Use and Corruption
Implications for Its Management in South Africa
Edwin Muchapondwa, Kerri Brick, and Martine Visser
Abstract
The illegal exploitation of wild abalone in South Africa has been escalating since 1994, despite increased enforcement, leading to collapse in some sections of its range. South Africa banned all wild abalone fishing in 2008 but controversially reopened it in 2010. This paper formulates a poacher‘s model, taking into account the realities of the abalone terrain in South Africa—the prevalence of bribery, corruption, use of recreational drugs, and the high value of abalone—to explore why poaching has not subsided. The paper suggests two additional measures that might help ameliorate the situation: eliminating the demand side through enforcement targeted on organized crime, and ceding the resource to the local coastal communities. However, local communities need to be empowered to deal with organised crime groups. Complementary measures to bring back community patriotism will also be needed given the tattered social fabric of the local coastal communities.
Introduction
Abalone meat is considered a delicacy and an aphrodisiac, and people in some Asian countries think it can delay senility and increase fertility (Hauck and Sweijd 1999; Burgener 2005). The high financial value of abalone, coupled with the fact that it lives in the shallow intertidal zone, makes it particularly vulnerable to overexploitation and environmental factors (Hauck and Sweijd 1999; Plagányi and Butterworth 2009). By 2003, global abalone production levels fell to less than 10,000 tonnes, about one-third of the level three decades previously (Prince et al. 2008, as cited in Plagányi and Butterworth 2009).
The South African abalone fishery dates back to 1949 and is one of the oldest commercial abalone fisheries in the world (Tarr 1992). It ranks as one of the top five to ten wild abalone fisheries in the world, behind the abalone fisheries of Australia and Japan (Tarbath et al. 2003, as cited in Plagányi and Butterworth 2009). The South African abalone fishery is reliant on a single gastropod species, H. midae (locally called perlemoen), which lives in shallow beds of kelp, Ecklonia maxima (Tarr 1993). The commercial fishery is located on South Africa‘s west coast from Cape Columbine to Quoin Point.1 Since the early 1990s, the South African abalone fishery has declined considerably, due to a combination of two factors: an ecosystem change from the movement of West Coast rock lobsters (Jasus lalandii) into a section of its range and very high levels of illegal fishing (Plagányi and Butterworth 2009).2
In a bid to counter illegal harvesting, the fisheries authority, the Department of Marine and Coastal Management (MCM), has invested significantly more in fisheries compliance since the mid-1990s. Hauck and Kroese (2006) documented how MCM strengthened law enforcement in the late 1990s, creating a specialised unit that focused on marine offenses and increased shoreline patrolling. Formal and informal partnerships were established with other government departments to conduct joint investigations, and an Environmental Court was established in 2003, primarily to try abalone cases. MCM also instituted measures to minimize corruption, such as increasing the salaries of fishery control officers and setting up a telephone hotline. In addition to these initiatives, it also attempted to decrease fishing effort by systematically reducing the total allowable catch (TAC), which was reduced from 500 tonnes in 1999-2000 to 75 tonnes towards the end of 2007 (Tarr 2003).
However, these traditional management measures proved relatively ineffective. Abalone poaching remained widespread at high levels. By 2007, nearly the entire abalone catch of over 2,000 tonnes was estimated to be caught illegally (Raemaekers and Britz 2009).3 Indeed, the abalone fishery is extremely difficult to manage given the suite of factors simultaneously at play: the increased predation of sea urchins by West Coast rock lobster, the high value of the resource, the presence of highly-organised poaching syndicates, and the discontent with lack of proper redistribution of access rights following South Africa‘s transition to democracy (Hauck and Sweijd 1999; Steinberg 2005; Hauck and Kroese 2006; Raemaekers and Britz 2009).
The commercially fished area is divided into seven fishing zones, with four main fishing zones. The inshore region is particularly depleted: inshore abalone stocks have crashed in two of the zones and are predicted to be heavily depleted in the others. Plagányi and Butterworth (2009) suggested that there is little hope of medium-term recovery of the resource in the zones where it has crashed, even if illegal fishing were stopped. However, they further suggested that if illegal fishing could be appreciably curtailed, these zones might show some recovery. The commercial fishery was closed in February 2008 but reopened in July 2010 as the ban was not effective.
The rationalist approach to compliance assumes that fishermen base their decision to comply with regulation on economic gains, the probability of detection, and the severity of punishment. In this context, the role of law enforcement and deterrence in facilitating compliance is widely recognized (Hauck 2009). In fact, the policing effort has not been constant over time because, for example, in some years the government provided additional resources in an effort to curb the escalating poaching levels (Plagányi and Butterworth 2009). However, increased law enforcement alone has not substantially reduced poaching. The abalone stock assessment model by Plagányi and Butterworth (2009) highlighted large increases in illegal harvest over time. Their model also suggested that, on average, only 14% of all poached abalone are confiscated. Alternate explanations for illegal behavior must be explored in order to design appropriate responses to the abalone poaching problem.
In this context, we developed a dynamic model of abalone poaching to assess why increased enforcement has failed to achieve better compliance with the abalone fishery regulations. Drawing on the work of Becker (1968), Ehrlich (1973), Messer (2000), and Abbott (2008), we formulated a specific South African model consisting of two agents: the conservation agency, MCM, which is responsible for protecting the abalone resource through enforcement activites; and the poacher, who divides time between legitimate employment and illegal abalone harvesting. We analyze why increased enforcement efforts have failed to curb illegal abalone harvesting by considering additional factors behind the illegal exploitation of abalone.
Our model allowed us to explore the relationship between abalone poaching, the high value of the abalone resource, corruption in enforcement structures, and other livelihood pressures whose resolution requires the use of harvested abalone (e.g., the trade of abalone in exchange for methamphetamines, consumption of which is inelastic because it is addictive). The inclusion of these additional factors enabled us to explain continued abalone poaching in the face of increased law enforcement effort and to suggest possible future policy directions. The paper proceeds as follows. The section that follows gives more background information. Next, the model is outlined, then relevant policy implications are discussed. The last section concludes.
Background
Abalone spawns by broadcasting. The planktonic larvae typically drift with the sea currents for about a week. They settle mostly in shallow inshore waters, where they seek shelter under boulders, narrow rock crevices, or under the spines of sea urchins Parechinus angulosus. At around 100 mm shell size (a sufficiently large size to have some protection from predation), they emerge and find a suitable habitat to attach to and let food come to them by water
movements. As their size slowly increases, the abalone may gradually disperse into deeper water (Plagányi and Butterworth 2009). They are slow growing, requiring a period of about seven years to attain 100% sexual maturity, and eight to nine years to attain the legal minimum catch size of 114 mm shell breadth.
Widespread poaching was prevalent during South Africa‘s transition to democracy in 1994. The 1994 ―abalone war,‖ which entailed violent confrontations between poachers, police, community members, and commercial divers, has evolved into a highly organized illegal transnational trading operation involving Chinese organized crime syndicates (Hauck and Kroese 2006). Gastrow (2001) described police investigations that revealed that illicit abalone trading constituted a significant share of the business of Chinese organized crime. Steinberg (2005) attributed the rapid growth in illicit abalone trading in the 1990s to a number of factors: weakness of the South African rand against the U.S. dollar, which provided significant incentive to ramp up the export of high-value, dollar-denominated commodities; an entrenched Chinese organized crime network in South Africa, with illicit trade routes between East Asia and South Africa, which bartered drugs for abalone;4 South Africa‘s difficulty with effective border control; and, finally, increased tolerance towards poaching by previously disadvantaged coastal communities frustrated by the perceived slow racial transformation of the country‘s fisheries. The presence of street gangs and international syndicates has not only increased pressure on the abalone resource, but also has compounded the complexity of resource management (Hauck 2009a).
The link between abalone and drug use is well documented. Steinberg (2005) described how, in the mid-1990s, players from the Western Cape‘s gang-based drug trade moved to abalone-rich fishing communities, taking control of huge segments of the abalone market. During this time, large quantities of the chemical ingredients for methaqualone—then the drug of choice in the Cape Flats—– were being smuggled into South Africa from East Asia. It was clear by the late 1990s that methaqualone was being bartered for abalone, and had been for some time (Steinberg 2005).
Abalone was completely intertwined in the illicit economy in the Western Cape: Chinese organized crime bartered cheap chemical precursors for methaqualone for valuable abalone; Western Cape drug dealers bartered cheaply-acquired abalone for high value drugs; and poachers exchanged abalone for drugs for resale or their own consumption (Steinberg 2005). Chinese organized crime still remains entangled in the Cape Flats drug market amid the rise in popularity of another recreational drug, colloquially called tik, or crystal methamphetamine (Steinberg 2005). Hauck (2009a) argued that the illegal exploitation of abalone has evolved into its own organized illicit industry controlled by street gangs at the shore and transnational syndicates which export the abalone to the Far East.
The international trade in abalone is primarily driven by demand in Asia. The main importers of abalone are Hong Kong, China, Japan, Malaysia, South Korea, Philippines, Singapore, and Taiwan, with Hong Kong as the largest importer (Allen et al. 2006; Burgener 2009).
As for exports of abalone, Allen et al. (2006) used trade statistics from the Hong Kong Census and Statistics Department to break down the countries of origin of preserved abalone imported into Hong Kong between 1998 and 2002. South Africa‘s and Mozambique‘s contributions were 19% and 11%, respectively. Nine countries categorised as ―others‖ contributed an estimated 12%. The majority of ―others‖ are African countries: Madagascar, Mauritius, Namibia, Senegal, Swaziland, Zambia, and Zimbabwe. Allen et al. (2006) noted that abalone is not indigenous to these countries, with the exception of Namibia, so it is likely that the abalone was poached in South Africa, smuggled into these other African countries, and exported from them to Hong Kong. The authors estimated that, factoring in the movement of abalone from other countries to South Africa, South Africa contributes around 40% of Hong Kong‘s preserved abalone imports.
Steinberg (2005) concluded that, while it is not possible to quantify the amount of abalone being smuggled across South Africa‘s borders, the majority of abalone is smuggled across its uncontrolled and commercial land borders and on unlogged air flights. Once the abalone has crossed over into neighboring states—where there is no law against the transportation or shipment of abalone without a permit—it is exported from sea and air ports. The latest data reported by Burgener (2009) confirms the presence of abalone exports from Kenya, Mozambique, Swaziland, and Zimbabwe, where abalone is not native.
H. midae was listed in Appendix 3 of the Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora in May 2007, which may have caused an increase in fraudulent declarations of abalone consignments. Indeed, international trade data reflected an apparent decrease in poached abalone from South Africa for the period 2004–2008, which could be due to either a reduction in the volume of illegal harvest and trade or an increase in mis-declarations in international trade. The decline in the volume of abalone exports from South Africa might also be due to a decrease in the average size of poached abalone. Furthermore, all poached abalone may not be exported immediately; it can be dried and sold later when anti-poaching enforcement becomes easier to evade (Burgener 2009). Based on the results from Plagányi and Butterworth (2009), abalone poaching is still strong and confiscation rates are low. There is thus a need and an opportunity for authorities to better understand the poaching problem and design more effective responses.
Anti-poaching enforcement officers use paid time to earn additional income from apprehended poachers, whom they decide to let go scot-free after paying them bribes. Eventually, the poachers internalize the bribes as any other ordinary cost of their harvesting activities. Thus, the prevalence of bribes increases poaching effort and consequently leads to over-exploitation of the resource.
Due to the existence of a number of factors that hinder anti-poaching enforcement, the size of anti-poaching enforcement is not necessarily related to its effectiveness. There might be ways of raising the probability of apprehension without necessarily increasing anti-poaching enforcement. With corruption, the effectiveness of any level of anti-poaching enforcement will be lower. By getting rid of corruption, the effectiveness of anti-poaching effort would increase.
So, what mechanisms can one use to get rid of corruption? In real life, one needs another enforcement activity—an anti-corruption enforcement effort and expense. However, a simpler way is to preach ethical behavior to the enforcement officials, hoping that they will change their own behavior. Investment in community education about the ecology and socioeconomics of abalone might also encourage the community to become involved and assist government enforcement.
The last factor influencing the dynamics of poaching behavior is the price of abalone. At present, abalone demand is inelastic, due to its association with status in Asia; thus, there is always big money to be made from the abalone business. When this is put against the background of the alternative sources of income to which poachers have access, there is no doubt that the lucrative abalone poaching will continue unless drastic measures are taken to curb it.
One option for dealing with abalone poaching would be to eliminate the demand side. The gangs act as monopsony by buying abalone from the local divers and monopoly by supplying abalone to the Chinese dealers. If enforcement were focused on gangs and on the Chinese dealers, or at least on their abalone activities, then one could eradicate the source of income for abalone poachers and remove their incentives to harvest. This is likely to work, given that most of the abalone is harvested by local harvesters for sale rather than own consumption.
Drastic measures focusing on creating an effective monitoring and enforcement mechanism are also needed. One option is to give local coastal communities the authority to manage the resource. This would also address the previous concern of community alienation from the abalone resource. Under such an arrangement, the government could cede property rights of particular sea beds to the coastal communities, ask them to manage the resource, and let them experience the consequences of their management actions. Thus, all net benefits from the resource will accrue to the coastal communities. Given the need to protect income-generating opportunities for some members, such as divers, the coastal communities might elect some of themselves as harvesters. These harvesters could pay rents to the rest of the community. If exploitation is not restrained, then communities themselves will suffer direct losses over time in terms of reduced rents.
In fact, South African authorities once flirted with this idea, but never fleshed it out. There are obvious challenges that have to be addressed for this co-management arrangement to work. As the model above shows, the poacher group is made up of divers from the local coastal communities and gang members. With co-management, the property rights will become entrenched in the local coastal communities. This arrangement gives resource monitoring responsibilities to the local coastal communities and paves the way for self-monitoring. However, the challenge is how to handle the gang members, who are usually external to the local coastal communities.
Co-management would alienate one powerful interest group, the gangs. In addition, the members of the coastal communities themselves are not homogenous. Some are divers, whose livelihoods depend on being in the water, while others are not. While divers can easily be allocated a harvesting quota and required to pay rent to the broader community, the same arrangement is not likely to be enforceable with gangs, which are powerful stakeholders. The gangs will readily disregard any local rules and regulations that the local community may put in place and will resort to violence. They may threaten any members of the community involved in policing or enforcement.
Thus, if co-management is to work, local communities must be empowered to deal with competing interest groups that want access to the resource, some of whom have access to weapons. A specialized police force might be created to assist the local community in tackling gangs determined to keep their access to the abalone resource. The key role of the coastal communities might be as little as being informants. Complementary measures to restore the common will of the community will also be needed, because the history of illegal abalone fishing has left the social fabric of the local coastal communities tattered.
[...]
As pointed out earlier, abalone poaching is entangled with drugs. Abalone is an easy source of income for gang members with which to buy the drugs necessary for gang activities. There has been a reported increase in the prevalence of drug use in South Africa, especially methampthetamines. Such a surge in the demand for drugs results in a rise in their prices. Because the quantity of drugs demanded does not respond much when prices rise, drug users have to secure additional income to finance the drug price increase. It is believed that the source of this additional finance has been dealing in illegal abalone, fueling continued poaching despite enforcement efforts. Thus, a fight against abalone poaching will necessarily be a fight against drug use, especially methamphetamine use with its intimate relationship with abalone poaching. Almost all of the illegally harvested abalone in South Africa is exported to Hong Kong. The delivery of illegally harvested abalone to local processing houses and to ports for export should be very difficult with alert enforcement efforts, given the vast distances involved. It appears, then, that enforcement is being compromised somehow, which aids the unabated and illicit abalone trade. There have been reports of police vehicles being used to transport poached abalone in order to avoid capture while in transit. In some cases, top political figures have been implicated in faciliating abalone movements. The role of this general corruption is then to reduce the probability of apprehension, allow poaching (effort) to continue and to further degrade the resource.
Another specific type of corruption, reported to be prevalent in South Africa, is bribery.
In the presence of bribery possibilities, the investment in enforcement is rendered ineffective.
Anti-poaching enforcement officers use paid time to earn additional income from apprehended poachers, whom they decide to let go scot-free after paying them bribes. Eventually, the poachers internalize the bribes as any other ordinary cost of their harvesting activities. Thus, the prevalence of bribes increases poaching effort and consequently leads to over-exploitation of the resource.
Due to the existence of a number of factors that hinder anti-poaching enforcement, the size of anti-poaching enforcement is not necessarily related to its effectiveness. There might be ways of raising the probability of apprehension without necessarily increasing anti-poaching enforcement. With corruption, the effectiveness of any level of anti-poaching enforcement will be lower. By getting rid of corruption, the effectiveness of anti-poaching effort would increase.
So, what mechanisms can one use to get rid of corruption? In real life, one needs another enforcement activity—an anti-corruption enforcement effort and expense. However, a simpler way is to preach ethical behavior to the enforcement officials, hoping that they will change their own behavior. Investment in community education about the ecology and socioeconomics of abalone might also encourage the community to become involved and assist government enforcement.
The last factor influencing the dynamics of poaching behavior is the price of abalone. At present, abalone demand is inelastic, due to its association with status in Asia; thus, there is always big money to be made from the abalone business. When this is put against the background of the alternative sources of income to which poachers have access, there is no doubt that the lucrative abalone poaching will continue unless drastic measures are taken to curb it.
One option for dealing with abalone poaching would be to eliminate the demand side. The gangs act as monopsony by buying abalone from the local divers and monopoly by supplying abalone to the Chinese dealers. If enforcement were focused on gangs and on the Chinese dealers, or at least on their abalone activities, then one could eradicate the source of income for abalone poachers and remove their incentives to harvest. This is likely to work, given that most of the abalone is harvested by local harvesters for sale rather than own consumption.
Drastic measures focusing on creating an effective monitoring and enforcement mechanism are also needed. One option is to give local coastal communities the authority to manage the resource. This would also address the previous concern of community alienation from the abalone resource. Under such an arrangement, the government could cede property rights of particular sea beds to the coastal communities, ask them to manage the resource, and let them experience the consequences of their management actions. Thus, all net benefits from the resource will accrue to the coastal communities. Given the need to protect income-generating opportunities for some members, such as divers, the coastal communities might elect some of themselves as harvesters. These harvesters could pay rents to the rest of the community. If exploitation is not restrained, then communities themselves will suffer direct losses over time in terms of reduced rents.
In fact, South African authorities once flirted with this idea, but never fleshed it out. There are obvious challenges that have to be addressed for this co-management arrangement to work. As the model above shows, the poacher group is made up of divers from the local coastal communities and gang members. With co-management, the property rights will become entrenched in the local coastal communities. This arrangement gives resource monitoring responsibilities to the local coastal communities and paves the way for self-monitoring. However, the challenge is how to handle the gang members, who are usually external to the local coastal communities.
Co-management would alienate one powerful interest group, the gangs. In addition, the members of the coastal communities themselves are not homogenous. Some are divers, whose livelihoods depend on being in the water, while others are not. While divers can easily be allocated a harvesting quota and required to pay rent to the broader community, the same arrangement is not likely to be enforceable with gangs, which are powerful stakeholders. The gangs will readily disregard any local rules and regulations that the local community may put in place and will resort to violence. They may threaten any members of the community involved in policing or enforcement.
Thus, if co-management is to work, local communities must be empowered to deal with competing interest groups that want access to the resource, some of whom have access to weapons. A specialized police force might be created to assist the local community in tackling gangs determined to keep their access to the abalone resource. The key role of the coastal communities might be as little as being informants. Complementary measures to restore the common will of the community will also be needed, because the history of illegal abalone fishing has left the social fabric of the local coastal communities tattered.
Conclusion
The illegal exploitation of abalone in South Africa has been escalating since the early 1990s. The South African government issued a ban on all wild abalone fishing in South Africa, effective February 2008, but controversially reopened in July 2010. This study explores the relationship between abalone poaching, use of methamphetamine drugs, criminal activity in the coastal communities of South Africa, and the associated implications for co-management of the abalone resource. The study formulates a model which is used to identify and appraise the likely effects of various policy instruments in curbing abalone poaching.
Like many other studies, this paper also includes increased anti-poaching enforcement and higher fines as ways to curb illegal harvesting. However, we also argue for more measures to curb illegal abalone harvesting in the South African context. The paper puts forward the role of drugs, general corruption, the prevalence of bribery, and the high value of abalone as possible explanations for why poaching has continued unabated. Two suggestions for dealing with abalone poaching are eliminating the demand side through targeted enforcement and ceding the resource to the local coastal communities. However, local communities need to be empowered to deal with criminal interest groups with access to instruments of violence. Complementary measures to bring back the community common is also needed, given the fragmented social situation of the local coastal communities.
Abalone Poaching
Abalone Poaching
Download full paper on Abalone Poaching
- Sprocky
- Posts: 7110
- Joined: Sat May 19, 2012 12:29 pm
- Country: South Africa
- Location: Grietjie Private Reserve
- Contact:
Re: Abalone Poaching
Once again it is the Asians!!
Sometimes it’s not until you don’t see what you want to see, that you truly open your eyes.
- Sprocky
- Posts: 7110
- Joined: Sat May 19, 2012 12:29 pm
- Country: South Africa
- Location: Grietjie Private Reserve
- Contact:
Perlemoen poaching hits 283 tons
Perlemoen poaching hits 283 tons
Published: 2013/05/27 10:09:00 AM
Source: SAPA
Cape Town - At least 283 tons of perlemoen (abalone) have been poached off South Africa's shores in the past few years, the Cape Times reported on Monday.
Fisheries Minister Tina Joemat-Pettersson reportedly said 58 tons were confiscated in 2012, 71 tons in 2011, 54 tons in 2009, and 43 tons in 2008.
This included both wet (shucked or shelled perlemoen) and dry perlemoen.
"It is very difficult to obtain precise data on the quantity of abalone poached because illegal catches are, by their very nature, unregulated and unreported, Joemat-Pettersson was quoted as saying in a written reply to a question in Parliament.
Published: 2013/05/27 10:09:00 AM
Source: SAPA
Cape Town - At least 283 tons of perlemoen (abalone) have been poached off South Africa's shores in the past few years, the Cape Times reported on Monday.
Fisheries Minister Tina Joemat-Pettersson reportedly said 58 tons were confiscated in 2012, 71 tons in 2011, 54 tons in 2009, and 43 tons in 2008.
This included both wet (shucked or shelled perlemoen) and dry perlemoen.
"It is very difficult to obtain precise data on the quantity of abalone poached because illegal catches are, by their very nature, unregulated and unreported, Joemat-Pettersson was quoted as saying in a written reply to a question in Parliament.
Sometimes it’s not until you don’t see what you want to see, that you truly open your eyes.
Perlemoen poaching on the rise
Perlemoen poaching on the rise
June 18 2013 at 06:00pm
By JOHN YELD
Cape Town - Despite a 40 percent increase in anti-poaching efforts by the authorities in recent years, abalone (perlemoen) poaching continues to grow.
And of particular concern is that some 60 percent of poached abalone is below reproductive age and levels of poaching are “far higher” than the total estimated sustainable catch from this resource, parliament’s portfolio committee on agriculture, forestry and fisheries has been told.
At a briefing last week on the status of South Africa’s marine fisheries by the national Department of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries, the committee was told that the abalone resource had suffered “a serious decline despite the best efforts at management”.
These efforts included the closure of the recreational fishery, “drastic” reductions in TACs (total allowable catches, or quotas), the introduction of the so-called “Turf” system whereby local coastal communities are given quotas and are expected in return to protect local abalone stocks, and even the closure of the commercial abalone fishery in 2008, although it was conditionally re-opened in 2010.
Although abalone numbers continued to drop because of poaching, projections indicated that recovery was possible if poaching could be reduced. “The recovery plan includes gradual increases in TACs if poaching can be reduced by 15 percent a year.”
The briefing document also revealed that the West Coast rock lobster (kreef) resource was currently “severely depleted”, with the catch having declined from a high of more than 18 000 tons in the 1950s to just over 2 000 tons now, for various reasons.
“Indications are that the resource is responding (to a recovery plan) but it is still too early to say with certainty.”
Referring to linefish, the document states that
“intense” fishing pressure has led to the widespread depletion of linefish stocks and catches are now far smaller than they were in the 1980s and 1990s.
“Emergency measures in place since 2000 appear to be having results for some linefish species at least; these measures need to remain in place for sufficient time to rebuild stocks to levels that will allow larger catches. If recovery to sustainable levels can be affected, the linefishery offers huge potential for growth and expansion.”
It notes that hake is still the only South African fishery certified by the international Marine Stewardship Council, and the value of the two species – shallow-water and deep-water hake – that are trawled inshore and offshore, and caught on longlines and by handline, equals that of all the other marine fisheries combined.
South Africa’s commercial fishing industry is valued at about R2-billion annually and employs some 27 000 people.
The presentation concluded: “The bad news is that many of our key marine fishery resources have been over-fished in the past. Our (fish) resources are therefore impoverished and catches are often far less than they could be.” - Cape Argus
June 18 2013 at 06:00pm
By JOHN YELD
Cape Town - Despite a 40 percent increase in anti-poaching efforts by the authorities in recent years, abalone (perlemoen) poaching continues to grow.
And of particular concern is that some 60 percent of poached abalone is below reproductive age and levels of poaching are “far higher” than the total estimated sustainable catch from this resource, parliament’s portfolio committee on agriculture, forestry and fisheries has been told.
At a briefing last week on the status of South Africa’s marine fisheries by the national Department of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries, the committee was told that the abalone resource had suffered “a serious decline despite the best efforts at management”.
These efforts included the closure of the recreational fishery, “drastic” reductions in TACs (total allowable catches, or quotas), the introduction of the so-called “Turf” system whereby local coastal communities are given quotas and are expected in return to protect local abalone stocks, and even the closure of the commercial abalone fishery in 2008, although it was conditionally re-opened in 2010.
Although abalone numbers continued to drop because of poaching, projections indicated that recovery was possible if poaching could be reduced. “The recovery plan includes gradual increases in TACs if poaching can be reduced by 15 percent a year.”
The briefing document also revealed that the West Coast rock lobster (kreef) resource was currently “severely depleted”, with the catch having declined from a high of more than 18 000 tons in the 1950s to just over 2 000 tons now, for various reasons.
“Indications are that the resource is responding (to a recovery plan) but it is still too early to say with certainty.”
Referring to linefish, the document states that
“intense” fishing pressure has led to the widespread depletion of linefish stocks and catches are now far smaller than they were in the 1980s and 1990s.
“Emergency measures in place since 2000 appear to be having results for some linefish species at least; these measures need to remain in place for sufficient time to rebuild stocks to levels that will allow larger catches. If recovery to sustainable levels can be affected, the linefishery offers huge potential for growth and expansion.”
It notes that hake is still the only South African fishery certified by the international Marine Stewardship Council, and the value of the two species – shallow-water and deep-water hake – that are trawled inshore and offshore, and caught on longlines and by handline, equals that of all the other marine fisheries combined.
South Africa’s commercial fishing industry is valued at about R2-billion annually and employs some 27 000 people.
The presentation concluded: “The bad news is that many of our key marine fishery resources have been over-fished in the past. Our (fish) resources are therefore impoverished and catches are often far less than they could be.” - Cape Argus
-
- Posts: 743
- Joined: Fri Jun 01, 2012 5:50 am
- Country: South Africa
- Location: Here but not all There
- Contact:
Large perlemoen bust in Free State
Large perlemoen bust in Free State
2013-07-15 21:38
Bloemfontein - Two Chinese men have been caught near Bloemfontein in possession of seven bags of perlemoen, police said on Monday.
They were arrested at a police checkpoint on the M10 between Bloemfontein and Dewetsdorp on Sunday, Captain Chaka Marope said.
Seven plastic bags containing a large amount of perlemoen (abalone) with an estimated street value of R90 000 were found in the boot of their car.
The men, aged 26 and 27, were from Cape Town en route to Lesotho. They would appear in the Bloemfontein Magistrate’s Court on Tuesday facing charges of unlawful possession of abalone.
- SAPA
2013-07-15 21:38
Bloemfontein - Two Chinese men have been caught near Bloemfontein in possession of seven bags of perlemoen, police said on Monday.
They were arrested at a police checkpoint on the M10 between Bloemfontein and Dewetsdorp on Sunday, Captain Chaka Marope said.
Seven plastic bags containing a large amount of perlemoen (abalone) with an estimated street value of R90 000 were found in the boot of their car.
The men, aged 26 and 27, were from Cape Town en route to Lesotho. They would appear in the Bloemfontein Magistrate’s Court on Tuesday facing charges of unlawful possession of abalone.
- SAPA
- Sprocky
- Posts: 7110
- Joined: Sat May 19, 2012 12:29 pm
- Country: South Africa
- Location: Grietjie Private Reserve
- Contact:
Foreigners held in Joburg for perlemoen
2013-10-25 10:09
Johannesburg - Two foreigners were arrested in Booysens, Johannesburg, on Thursday for possession of dried perlemoen [abalone] worth about R1.5m, the Hawks said on Thursday.
The men were arrested at a house in the Hill, near Booysens, after a tip-off, said spokesperson Paul Ramaloko.
The arrests follow those of two Chinese men on 14 October in Pretoria. They were caught with dried perlemoen worth about R600 000.
Possession of perlemoen contravenes the Marine Living Resources Act. South Africa banned abalone fishing in 2008.
"They will appear in the Johannesburg Magistrate's Court [on Friday]. They are charged with possession of abalone," said Ramaloko.
- SAPA
Johannesburg - Two foreigners were arrested in Booysens, Johannesburg, on Thursday for possession of dried perlemoen [abalone] worth about R1.5m, the Hawks said on Thursday.
The men were arrested at a house in the Hill, near Booysens, after a tip-off, said spokesperson Paul Ramaloko.
The arrests follow those of two Chinese men on 14 October in Pretoria. They were caught with dried perlemoen worth about R600 000.
Possession of perlemoen contravenes the Marine Living Resources Act. South Africa banned abalone fishing in 2008.
"They will appear in the Johannesburg Magistrate's Court [on Friday]. They are charged with possession of abalone," said Ramaloko.
- SAPA
Sometimes it’s not until you don’t see what you want to see, that you truly open your eyes.
- nan
- Posts: 26448
- Joined: Thu May 31, 2012 9:41 pm
- Country: Switzerland
- Location: Central Europe
- Contact:
Re: Foreigners held in Joburg for perlemoen
is it for the nacre... or to eat
Kgalagadi lover… for ever
https://safrounet.piwigo.com/
https://safrounet.piwigo.com/
- Sprocky
- Posts: 7110
- Joined: Sat May 19, 2012 12:29 pm
- Country: South Africa
- Location: Grietjie Private Reserve
- Contact:
2 appear over R1m worth of perlemoen
2013-11-18 22:10
Johannesburg - Two men appeared in the Beaufort West Magistrate's Court on Monday for possession of perlemoen worth an estimated R1m, Western Cape police said.
Thembazami Boyisi, 36, and Vusumzi Mongameli, 32, both from Strand, Cape Town, were arrested on 14 November while travelling on the N1 through Beaufort West to Johannesburg, said police spokesperson Malcolm Pojie.
About 6 648 perlemoen in 67 bags were found when police stopped and searched their car.
The two would appear in court again on 25 November for a bail application.
- SAPA
Johannesburg - Two men appeared in the Beaufort West Magistrate's Court on Monday for possession of perlemoen worth an estimated R1m, Western Cape police said.
Thembazami Boyisi, 36, and Vusumzi Mongameli, 32, both from Strand, Cape Town, were arrested on 14 November while travelling on the N1 through Beaufort West to Johannesburg, said police spokesperson Malcolm Pojie.
About 6 648 perlemoen in 67 bags were found when police stopped and searched their car.
The two would appear in court again on 25 November for a bail application.
- SAPA
Sometimes it’s not until you don’t see what you want to see, that you truly open your eyes.
SA set to cancel perlemoen quotas
SA set to cancel perlemoen quotas
2014-05-23 10:33
Cape Town – Communities that rely on the perlemoen industry will have to brace themselves as commercial perelemoen quotas may be cancelled.
According to a report by Die Burger, Forestry and Fisheries Minister Tina Joemat-Pettersson is set to cancel commercial perelemoen fishing.
Joemat-Pettersson bases this decision on the dwindling breeding population.
This will be a heavy blow to divers who rely on the perlemoen industry for their livelihood.
Stephen Maree, a commercial diver was shocked at the possibility and believes that government has no right to take away this from the community.
In 2012 Parliament issued a warning, that quotas could be cancelled because of poaching.
Joemat-Pettersson noted that a public meeting will be held with community representatives in Towns like Hawston in the southern Cape.
The minister also said that alternatives would be given to communities. Divers may have the opportunity to instead catch red steenbras.
The perlemoen industry is roughly worth R100m a year according to Die Burger.
There is a huge concern that this banning may increase perlemoen poaching , according to the department spokesperson, Lionel Adendorf.
Poachers should be aware that there are more resources being allocated in order to decrease perlemoen poaching.
In January five men were arrested in Cape Town for illegal possession of perlemoen worth an estimated R1.5m.
Police found 18 676 perlemoen pieces, nine unshelled perlemoen and crayfish.
Perlemoen grows slowly and reach sexual maturity only after 7 years according to the City of Cape Town.
2014-05-23 10:33
Cape Town – Communities that rely on the perlemoen industry will have to brace themselves as commercial perelemoen quotas may be cancelled.
According to a report by Die Burger, Forestry and Fisheries Minister Tina Joemat-Pettersson is set to cancel commercial perelemoen fishing.
Joemat-Pettersson bases this decision on the dwindling breeding population.
This will be a heavy blow to divers who rely on the perlemoen industry for their livelihood.
Stephen Maree, a commercial diver was shocked at the possibility and believes that government has no right to take away this from the community.
In 2012 Parliament issued a warning, that quotas could be cancelled because of poaching.
Joemat-Pettersson noted that a public meeting will be held with community representatives in Towns like Hawston in the southern Cape.
The minister also said that alternatives would be given to communities. Divers may have the opportunity to instead catch red steenbras.
The perlemoen industry is roughly worth R100m a year according to Die Burger.
There is a huge concern that this banning may increase perlemoen poaching , according to the department spokesperson, Lionel Adendorf.
Poachers should be aware that there are more resources being allocated in order to decrease perlemoen poaching.
In January five men were arrested in Cape Town for illegal possession of perlemoen worth an estimated R1.5m.
Police found 18 676 perlemoen pieces, nine unshelled perlemoen and crayfish.
Perlemoen grows slowly and reach sexual maturity only after 7 years according to the City of Cape Town.